By Son of Bastiat
“I’m not the 1 %. I’m not the 99 %. I’m me” – Vinnie, a self-made art entrepreneur
One of these days, without wishing that fate on them, an Occupier, a pedestrian, a bystander along with scores of others will have their asses kicked, heads cracked, ribs broken, limbs severed or worse, in an orgy of violence that will erupt over issues that few of them have clearly grasped, and thus have little chance to influence: economic justice, income distribution, bankers’ greed, corporate power, welfare or whatever other causes of their disempowerment. Apart from providing critical mass and excitement that liberal media love to hype, they will end up as little more than cannon fodder for clever agitators with more focused and sinister agenda, the useful fools that revolutions since time immemorial have relied on for the dirty job of capturing mass movements that just as quickly fade into egoistic fantasies.
When it happens they will experience the imperfect, unforgiving world first hand. They will learn about the millions who, just like them aspire to better lives, but the pursuit of which result in making life less than ideal for themselves and everybody else. They will meet the legions who, day after day, suffer the cruel stings of unintended consequences, their best efforts and purest intentions notwithstanding. Maybe they’ll appreciate how sordid the “human condition” is, from which their efforts to escape embroil them in all sorts of transference problems. If they’re lucky they’ll learn how the complications in their lives grow in proportion to the degree they fantasize “how the world ought to be”, rather than “seeing it as it is”. They might conclude that much of their beef about life is delusion willfully indulged.
Parsing Egalitarian Entrails
They hate it that the world is too unequal? Well, so do I, but to get anywhere, a precise definition of “inequality” is needed. Time magazine offers one aspect of it: average incomes of $ 1.5 MM and $ 50,000 for the 1 % and 99 % of all Americans respectively. But do they really think that eliminating differences between two figures is all there is to it? Sadly it isn’t, because income (or wealth) gaps hide more things than are apparent on the surface. Just ask: will dragging the 1 % down and bringing the 99 % up make things better? The answer is no, because even if the latter are numerically superior, it punishes the few “heavy lifters” and rewards lots of underperformers, with the result that society as a whole ends up less productive.
And why should productivity matter? Because in the long run, redistributions that do not ensure wealth creation end up making things worse – just look at how farmers who receive land after land reform without provisions for making them productive promptly lose them, leaving agriculture worse off than before. Instead of bringing people down it would be better to create opportunities; taking away the fruits of work of the 1 % will lead to a capital strike that reduces those opportunities. Few Occupiers realize that this nasty “come back” is what causes their joblessness.
But what if perceptions of “just” differences are frivolous or subjective? If there is no objective basis for doing it, income and wealth will be redistributed with neither the support of givers nor the gratitude of recipients. It’ll not be easy but even assuming that it can be done, keeping it there will require constant infringements on every one’s freedom or expectations, which as Machiavelli pointed out, endears the egalitarian to neither. Thus redistributions don’t last long, especially if people are free to do what they
want, from refusing to create wealth to running away from it altogether (now rampant in the US and even China) . Instead of removing inequalities, they only end up making them worse and permanent.
Voluntary redistributions via taxes are only a tad less chaotic, requiring one to reconcile peoples’ differing needs for, and respective contributions to the creation of that which is sought to be equalized. Unless everyone yields to reason or sense of moral worth, disagreement will lead to discontentment. Redistribution even with volition means that one doesn’t care how motivations and capacity to generate wealth are affected; all that matters is less inequality at whatever the consequences. Coercion can effect and maintain it, but eventually egalitarians will have to make up for what is lost in the process, with the result that the 99 % will have less income and no jobs. Such are the calculations of fantasists.
This is why the most practical distribution policy (Rawls’) aims not at full equality, but the toleration of some of it in exchange for motivating those who contribute more towards wealth creation and income generation, provided that that those at the lower end of the distribution scale are not made worse off as a result of the policy. It admits that no human society – even the most truculently egalitarian - can avoid inequality; it is a matter of how well members can tolerate it, and of where they have a better chance at rectifying it if they can’t. If that approach still creates too much inequality, blame those who formulated policies that produced such outcome, even if they did it in error; make them pay dearly for such outrage especially if they did it with malice. Just don’t redistribute wealth or income arbitrarily as not only would it fail to solve that problem, but will likely end up worsening it. To Proudhon’s “Wealth is theft” must be added: “Punish the thief, suffer the loss of what he gives you”. Even bad men do produce a lot of good.
Do You Understand the Moral Roots of Greed?
As with inequality, much depends on what “greed” exactly means and whose vice it is. Unlike inequality which is retrospective and is not an absolute requirement of growth, greed is prospective and central to the achievement of that growth. This is why greed is a double edged sword that can do a lot of good (when used by the right folks) or evil, if otherwise. What one can’t simply do is judge those who indulge in it, without inquiring as to why and what their roles are. Like inequality, perceptions about greed tend to be colored by subjective understanding of what is required in such roles. This is why folks find greed by others offensive (but not as much if done by themselves) – it’s the resentment in being excluded from the benefits especially if they don’t know whether they deserve them, or whether they can deliver what’s expected in those roles. Like inequality, greed defies analysis using subjective, overt comparisons; greed goes beyond by being self-referential, never looking at what the other side needs.
If those perceptual problems are not bad enough, one will also be held hostage by moral baggage that he acquired in the society he grew up. Philosophers have pointed out how moral judgments arise from extending beliefs outside of their proper boundaries, while psychologists link them to the mysterious operations of the subconscious, but let’s skip those because they require making shaky assumptions about the purpose and meaning of life. Let us focus on how thinking processes are affected by language and word usage, largely without individual awareness. It turns out that a lot (not all) of moral judgments flow from nothing more than beliefs shaped by personal, family, tribal and community values. A lot of moral judgments (again not all) have little to back them up save for local values (e.g., fairness, justice, etc) that a community holds as sacrosanct. To make matters worse, this error of thought is compounded by carelessness in sentence construction and meaning of words. To Vaggini errors of moral judgment result from illogical transpositions of the subject and object in certain types of sentence structures. As astonishing as that sounds, what the above claims mean is that excessive concern for greed (and also inequality) are the products of self-awareness; anything beyond that is pure, unadulterated fluff.
At any rate there is no need for these uneasy assumptions for there is a simpler explanation for the mental aberration that disposes one to view everything that does not align with his personal ideas of what is just, as greed and “therefore” immoral: the arrogant belief premised in one’s having ALL the facts needed to make a particular moral judgment. In today’s volatile and extremely complex world, that assumption betrays irrational hubris. How else to explain why, in the aftermath of the financial crisis, the sanctimonious quickly and totally blamed it on “greedy bankers” when, in light of perfect hindsight, it turns out that their legitimate roles (as a class, for particular behaviors can never be explained by any general theory) as maximizers of gains were enabled by bad regulation and politically tainted policies which relaxed origination standards and encouraged leverage in pursuit of a policy goal (mass housing).
Unlike politicians, the bankers were performing what they were trained to do, which is to generate profits within silo-like environments that were bereft of sufficient information and understanding, thus amplifying unknown events occurring elsewhere. Save for a prescient few who “boasted” of being right early on, the character and severity of the crisis was generally not foreseeable even by economists who lacked market insights and experience to predict it, let alone prove conclusively that an emergent system could not “right” itself, especially that what finally pushed the system over the cliff are not these mistakes but the flawed decisions of the system’s liquidity managers who erred in dealing with, what else, a no-precedent crisis. Folks who blame greed for the crisis sans any qualifiers (e.g., errors of judgment or irresponsible behavior under complexity), are at best being naïve about human behavior in dynamic systems; at worst they are romanticists who can’t psychologically cope with uncomfortable causes for events that they can’t mentally grasp, so they default to the easier search for demons to exorcise. The fact that conflicted “greed”, if properly harnessed is vital to wealth and job creation should caution those inclined towards simplistic judgments, to ponder the risks of demonizing a vital part of economic life. An inability to entertain two opposed ideas without hiding psychic baggage is a sign of a weak, delusional mind ever seeking relief in transference. Moral outrage is a sop to a guilty conscience.
The Dilemmas of Corporations and the Welfare State
Let’s go right to the heart of issues that protesters are correct to raise even if they can’t quite articulate them well: the legitimacy of Corporations because of the unprecedented powers they have amassed, both outside the sphere of market operations and in their ability to corrupt society through their strong influence over the political process. Who in his or her right mind would question such motive, but it is also true that such ideal goals involve tradeoffs at a stiff price. But if that isn’t bad yet, Occupiers compound their woes by thinking that a non-market solution – the welfare state – can solve the problems they decry, namely slow economic and job growth. Like democracy, the corporation is far from being an ideal solution, save all other alternatives are worse – their tradeoffs are more expensive.
A little history should remind one that the modern corporation is a recent phenomenon, a caricature of the weak entity that it was in the last years of the 19th century or even up to the early years of the 20th. Massive needs for capital by technology, the imperative to diversify markets for stability of growth, and the centralization of authority to deal with efficiency issues and control the resulting complexity – all these led to the amassing of power (and thus its abuse) by those who lead these organizations. That most of them were self-appointed and not responsible to society or even to the corporation’s owners (who got castrated in the process) is not their fault; say what you want about the Law’s failure to come up with the proper legal safeguards or about regulators’ duties to properly enforce the rulings, the fact is that the corporation is the suboptimal solution that has successfully delivered on two of society’s most critical survival desiderata – employing the hundreds of thousands of its members who must earn a living at the least expenditure of time, money and effort; and effecting the efficient conversion of resources into sustainable growth. That many corporations have failed these tests or thwarted their attainment is no reason to reject all of them, unless one is sure that he has a superior alternative.
As one scans the landscape, he finds that few of those are worthwhile candidates to replace it. For the criteria boils down to what extent those vehicles’ decisions can take place within the influence of market discipline, especially as they undertake decisions that have non-market ramifications and “external” influences, such as is the character of social decisions today. The problem is that the boundaries delineating these decisions are booby-trapped with unknown costs and outcomes, which sets this back to the old nemesis, unanticipated consequences. Folks of a disposition akin to those we have met above – a moral repugnance for any inequality and the slightest hint of (unqualified) greed, prefer that non-market solutions predominate. What they claim little or no awareness of (or if they do, are uncomfortable to admit), is that such alternatives involve an explicit if seldom acknowledged tradeoff between two opposed ways of thinking about modern society: a market-responsive one typified by corporations (economically successful but rapacious if uncontrolled) and a non-market driven welfare state (inefficient, wasteful, unsustainable), its only tested alternative. The harsh reality is that one can only choose between two, imperfect solutions, but one of which tends to make the outcomes worse.
None of this defends (let alone excuses) the modern corporation’s hideous handiwork in vital concerns as environmental degradation, unsustainable exploitation of natural reserves, manufacture and exports of death-dealing weapons or drugs, aggressive lobbying to influence regulatory and electoral outcomes, all the way to outsourcing jobs that have no logic other than maintaining “competitive presence”. On the other hand, one has the welfare state, ostensibly set up to take care of those with neither the means nor the knowledge to protect themselves against the vagaries of nature or the rapacity of the markets. What it achieved instead was to siphon the resources that could have been used to get the economy to grow faster in order to lift those at the bottom of the social pyramid, which it diverted to politicians, bureaucrats and parties such as labor unions, with interests vested in perpetuating inefficiency and the sense of entitlements that resisted all reforms that threatened their hold over votes and sources of patronage. It is supreme irony the real threat to the world economy today comes not from the much excoriated “corporate greed” but from explosive public debt, a legacy of the welfare state. In matters that affect society the most – jobs and economic security- the corporate economy, warts and all, trumps the welfare state. To want to kill it while growing the welfare state is not only ludicrous but inane.
Hence the question is: what are Occupiers’ beef against corporations, and why their quixotic preference for such losers as the inept, inefficient and stodgy welfare state to deliver what is important to society? Could it be that the reason they condemn the corporate economy and praise the welfare state is that
they are psychologically insecure with competing in the marketplace where they can get their asses kicked in spite of a (academically indulged) pretense that they’re good. Well one is not THAT good if he must seek solace for his wounds from the womb-like comforts of a nanny, which the welfare state is. The tragedy is that Occupiers do not see that they are ditching imperfect solutions that work in favor of worse ones that have failed miserably, as close to the definition of delusion as one can have.
What Their Real Problem Is: Externalizing Inner Failures
Three years ago a young man asked to talk to me one on one. Thinking that it had to do with his long put off marriage plans, I braced for some unanticipated news: an unplanned wedding, or worse a split. As soon as he sat down gravely on the couch, I sensed that this was a devastating issue, and indeed it was: his job would not be renewed the very next year when he and his fiancé had planned to finally marry. I sat down silently as I listened to him detail the reason for the painful news: that despite being a talented art teacher, well-liked by peers and adored by his students, the artist in him just was not up to the administrative and routine demands of the job. As I observed his face turn grim and his eyes shed tears of anger, frustration and fear, I fought hard to explain and reassure him that being fired was not the end of the world; how I, too, once faced such a disaster, which I overcame by acquiring more expertise than my “firers”, which facilitated my foray into opportunities far beyond what I could find working for others. After going through this human moment we knew that there were serious things we had to do; none of those was about blaming our immigrant fates or the society that gave us our breaks. It was all about coping with life’s challenges as best as we can, as they unfolded in all of their stark harshness.
I wasn’t expecting to see how such an experience could be improved upon and surpassed by this young man who rose above this depressing episode, so well that in the span of less than three years, with a little less than a thousand dollars in seed money, he built a business that his peers now rate highly as an upcoming global sports art licensing and branding business, with fans from all corners of the world so rabid as to tattoo his art work on their bodies. Recently he capped this feat by co-branding and licensing his products to, and partnering as creative designer for, a leading US apparel firm that sells to 1,400 outlets. Looking at it now his dramatic turnaround owed mostly to personal discipline, adhesive-like perseverance, a refusal to get overwhelmed by lots of handicaps (we are outsiders), and a can-do spirit that drives him to excel amidst all odds. Instead of ending up as a loser he turned himself into a self-made entrepreneur who neither gave up nor depends on others for support, refusing to externalize his problems by blaming America for his share of life’s trials. Recently we had occasion to watch a rowdy O.W.S rally blaming the 1 % for their problems, and here is what he said: “I’m not the 1 %. I’m not the 99 %. I’m me, doing what I can to change the world”. I copyrighted and used it as the idea for this essay.
Other than the fact that terribly misguided can be useful in waking up society’s often moribund senses, there is not an iota of logic or fact to back up the O.W.S. positions, no matter how well meant and sincerely they are held. This is why they cannot come up with concrete proposals, and why they prefer to wallow in ambiguities, fearing that taking positions will force them to confront extremely painful realities, not the least being their conflicted inner selves. Why risk the embarrassment of a firm position when in vagueness one can indulge the airs of moral superiority? Could it be that this phenomenon called O.W.S. is the escapism of a bunch of badly raised losers who have succumbed to life’s vicissitudes and blamed America for their misfortunes?
Instead of wasting energy occupying idle real estate, why not build something concrete and useful on top of it?
Short, light but perceptive essays on contemporary events and the foibles of the men (and women) behind them that deserve to be praised (or ridiculed) in light of lessons from similar events in the past. A cross between polemic and tracts to ensure a healthy balance between rigor and rumor, leavened with lots of insights about human nature and their institutions. Accent is on humor and wit, without inflicting unnecessary discomfort.
Showing posts with label philosophy. Show all posts
Showing posts with label philosophy. Show all posts
Sunday, November 6, 2011
Monday, October 17, 2011
Debating the Philippine Reproductive Health Bill: A Commentary
By Son of Bastiat
“I
humbly submit that the struggle for an RH bill to protect the health and
quality of life of the mother and child in the context of unspeakable poverty
is part of liberation theology” adding that Vatican II taught the "primacy
of conscience." (Philippines Sen. Santiago’s remarks in a Sun Star 8/2/11 interview)
“There
is enough hard evidence in other countries that followed the same path of
population control, which shows that a contraceptive mentality inevitably leads
to a significant rise in abortion, divorce, single mothers and mentally
unbalanced adolescents”. (Dr. Villegas, Philippines’ economist in “Little
Chance for RH Bill” Inquirer.net,
10/15/11)
Like the Occupy Wall Street protesters’ shouts reverberating 3.5 miles away
from where this essay is being written, the above quotes read as if their
respective positions are clear and sufficiently “joined” as to make a reasoned
debate possible. In fact, that is far from being the case, if only because
these quotes occurred at two different times and media sources (an online
column and interview) and juxtaposed in a contrived debate to highlight the
essence of two diametrically opposed positions on the RH Bill. They represent
two radical opposed worldviews, neither one effectively articulated by their
advocates. Is it due to the RH Bill’s intrinsic complexity, modern man’s
intransigence, his pride? Or all of it combined?
EVALUATING THE CORE POSITIONS
Begin with the Senator’s views,
which her quote above succinctly summarizes:
a). Due to unspeakable poverty, an RH Bill will protect the health and
quality of mother and child. She makes no reference to the widespread view that
overpopulation promotes poverty, only that controlling it promotes human
welfare.
In claiming that an RH Bill will
protect the health and quality of life of families, she sidesteps but does not
avoid making the conclusion that overpopulation is a major cause of poverty. As
a legislator she is no doubt aware that much of the government’s budget is
appropriated for poverty amelioration; AND that scarce national resources
(land, oceans, etc.) are preempted for basic survival by a predominantly poor
and underproductive population. These factors are deemed to reduce the amount of
resources that can be used to “grow the pie” or improve its quality. With fewer
people, resources and income per capita are much higher. The correlation
between population size, per capita income, quality of life and wellbeing in
neighboring countries is cited “as proof” of the wisdom of population control
policy.
Bernie Villegas’ comments suggest
that while he agrees with this view in the short term, it is fraught with major
problems in the long run. He refrains from zeroing in on Santiago’s (and RH Bill
advocates) views that overpopulation reduces future growth potential, by citing
past research done by Clarke and more recently by Nobelist Gary Becker, to the
effect that this redirection of resources from future to current use accounts
for a much smaller impact on permanent growth than is being claimed based on
“commonsensical observations” drawn from experience which are almost always
biased. Assuming that it is huge, China’s situation should serve as a useful
reminder of this one-dimensional fallacy: even if its “One-Child-Per Family”
had allowed it to amass resources to bankroll its growth, how efficiently they
were used, what they brought China’s poor in exchange and where the policies
they encouraged are leading China today are far more important than the
simplistic resource mobilization issue it addressed.
These statements ought to caution
those inclined towards casual empiricism (i.e., analyses drawn from random
experiences) from extending their individual conclusions into the realm of
aggregate and multi-generational policy making. This knowledge domain error
(see le Compte de Nouy) is more fatal than many RH Bill advocates realize and
yet is not pointed out to them by RH Bill opponents. It illustrates the
incompleteness of the debate. But why be surprised when the more basic
limitations of population-vs-growth models have not been recognized, despite
the known shortcomings of statistical analyses when set against the broader
context of scientific truth validation and theory of knowledge?
Score this round for the Senator,
but not because she out-argues Villegas on this false economic issue but for
the latter’s hedging, in hopes that RH Bill advocates will see that short term
tradeoffs between growth and population are not only spurious (“Even assuming,
without granting, that population control can help in the important task of
eradicating poverty. . .”) but nonsensical especially in the long run when more
factors other than economic growth matter. But that’s going ahead of our
essay.
Let’s then go to her second argument:
b). “Liberation Theology” and Vatican II have struck at the roots of social
inequality that an RH Bill is designed to mitigate, and the Church has a
“mission that includes the struggle on behalf of justice, peace, and human
rights." Humanae Vitae the encyclical on which the Church bases its
opposition to birth control was based on a “minority’ view, adding that 80% of
US Catholics do not follow it.
Let’s dispose of the easier part
of her position – that the real reason the encyclical Humane Vitae got adopted by the Church despite being held or
accepted only by a “minority” of Catholics, is that electors were railroaded
into passing it during the feverish route to Vatican II. Asserting that some encyclicals are passed
over the wishes of the “majority” is mainly a case of verification but the more
meaningful question is: can most matters of core importance to a Faith be
vetted by its followers? If it is the way a faith’s central tenets are decided,
then the crucial element of its unquestioned acceptance disappears; belief by
consensus simply means an absence of Faith. The fact that 80 % of members
profess to not follow a faith is not to be held against it; that simply means
that such Faith does not exist no matter what its members believe. To see why
this not solipsism or sophistry, consider what happened when Socialists began
to deviate from the strict principles laid down by Marx and Lenin. In due time
the socialist camp splintered into factions that ultimately got co-opted by
their adversaries (China’s “market socialism” being the best example). The only
reason Islam escaped this fate is because its coherence depends less on
doctrinal homogeneity and more on coercion. Even so, it is split into two
feuding sects.
Because the Church would not
countenance the temporal and totalitarian impulses that drive Socialism and
Islam, that existential risk is more serious in the Church’s case since its
doctrinal integrity depends on the acceptance of all individual tenets; reject
one and the entire edifice falls flat on its face. Absence of members’
coherence, rather than a radical change in one or more core tenets, explains
Santiago’s claim that “the absolute authority of the Church has grown weaker
over the years”.
This brings the second, major
fallacy in the Senator’s position: Liberation Theology. Santiago claims that
the RH Bill draws its legitimacy from the Church’ mission to help the poor but
as a Theology specialist, does she believe this? Is it the Church’s stated
central mission or merely one of the many avenues that it pursues while
carrying out its primary mission (of saving souls)? It surely cannot be the
primary one, if only because the Church is a transcendental institution that
finds it must minister to the temporal needs of its members. For the Church to
involve itself beyond this, even if not at the expense of its spiritual one,
would be to risk diluting its primary mission, with all the potential for
errors that involvement in social causes lead to. If this is not obvious to a
theology scholar, all she has to do is to review the Church’ mixed record of
advocating for social causes (e.g., the US bishops’ 70s disastrous position on
economic equality or of Archbishop H. Camara’s amateurish dabbling in Latin
American development). Suffice it to mention that some of the most spectacular
welfare and social justice program failures began as well-meaning religious
initiatives to help the poor. If in this fairly straightforward temporal area
the Church did a less than fully creditable job, what more with complex,
transcendental issues like birth control?
To put it bluntly the Church has
no excuse in involving itself in these debates for social justice reasons.
Villegas did not highlight this in his article at all, but again this omission,
just like the first above, is why RH Bill advocates, especially those carrying
religious baggage end up losing sight of, and getting more confused about their
primary position. I would score this at 0-0 as neither side floors the other
down.
And finally their third bone of contention:
c). Conscience is what matters above all, being “inviolable” and that a
Catholic has a right to follow her own conscience “even when it is erroneous”
(ie., meaning it goes against some “objective” standard).
Of all the Senator’s quotes, this
one is the most perplexing, both in point of logic and origin, coming as it
does from someone educated in theology and law. In the first place, an
erroneous conscience presupposes the existence of some kind of moral reference for
otherwise there would be no basis for assessing blame, which is the rationale
for that claim. But in using the term “erroneous” the Senator explicitly
declares that the Church’ tenets are not the only standard by which to base
such judgment. It leads her straight to the pre-modern era traps of
infallibility and relativism, which have been argued, fought, warred over and
resolved since medieval times, resulting in the outcome now known as the Great
Separation (not between Church and State but between Man and his Creator).
Here is where Villegas delivers
the knock-out punch. Briefly, the debate between the RH Bill advocates revolves
around whether Man’s wishes will prevail over God’s. Santiago herself starkly
states it: “In the past, Catholics simply
obeyed the bishops. But now, many Catholics are no longer willing to give blind
obedience to the Church”. But as pointed earlier, real faith not being a
matter of consensus, continued membership in it is a tacit admission that it
speaks for God (unless believers are schizophrenic dualists who by definition are deniers of one
truth). Villegas’ arguments center around the subtle point that going against
God’s will would in the long run be dangerous for Man, even if man refuses to
accept it as such. No Nobel economists are needed to prop this position up
because it indeed is what happens when man denies accountability to an entity
other than himself, regardless of whether it involves faith or not. It was the
ultimate (but never admitted) cause of the recent financial crisis. It is the
reason why the EU is now imploding into pieces, followed in due course by
China. It is what will happen to the Philippines if the RH Bill is passed into
law and the contraceptive mentality takes hold. Here’s what UK Prime Minister Cameron
attributed the recent rioting in London and nearby cities to: “Irresponsibility. Selfishness. Behaving as
if our choices have no consequences. Children without fathers. Schools without
discipline. Reward without effort”. (The Financial Times, 8/16/11). These
are the RH Bill’s longer term and secondary effects that one side ignores and
another sidesteps hoping it will just sink in. But it won’t.
What Villegas says is that
passing the RH Bill will perpetuate a cultural dependency and moral weakness
that abets all the ills that afflict contemporary Philippine society, with zero
assurance that the resources freed by controlling population growth can be
turned into material, let alone intangible benefits. It is the existential
risk, not the temporary trade-offs that make RH Bill’s passage disastrous. It
is just amazing that an ancient debate that has long been clarified, manages to
emerge in sophisticated raiment, revealing again that man’s pride doesn’t let
him learn from the wisdom that has been learned for ages. The theologian Barth
said. “Look around you. . .all you see is
chaos, irrationality and downright perversity of the world man has made for
himself. What was the mad carnage of the Great War but the predictable result
of humanism, which modern theologians celebrated rather than judged? They have
wished to experience the known god of this world”, Barth said, “Well! They have experienced him”.
CONCLUSION
This essay closes by quoting the
final paragraph of an essay that the author wrote assessing J. Burnham’s
classic 1964 book “The Suicide of the
West” (Gateway Editions):
How Western Societies Really Die
“What they are saying to us today is that if you want to keep the
Federal government open you have to throw women under the bus” is how Sen. P.
Murray (D., Wash) depicted the contentious budget debates among Republicans and
Democrats in which funding for Planned Parenthood (a pro-abortion group) came
close to shutting down the US government. The terrible fact is that the
economic future of the US is held hostage by an issue that doesn’t even
represent 0.15 % of a budget that liberals have larded with entitlements so
that 1-2 % cuts are “draconian” and sufficient to derail compromise. If the US
economy implodes it will not be from wars or invasions but from decisions that
made killing unborn babies kosher.
Far from stimulating the economy
in the way it supposedly did for its neighbors, the RH Bill will unleash
destructive values that will keep the Philippine economy from taking off. But
don’t count on “modern” RH Bill advocates to supply the antidote, because their
self-absorption and pride are too weak to detect it. Writing in Perspectives in Political Science,
Summer 2009 Volume 8 Issue 3, Ralph Hancock cited Hans Blumenberg’s view “that the modern age emerged from a movement
not of reason but of self-assertion, although the purity of this self-assertion
was obscured by attempts to respond to now meaningless questions left over from
the challenge of an essentially Gnostic nominalism”. Understanding the RH Bill’s dangers calls for
mastery of a difficult philosophical issue and tempering
man’s exaggerated view of the self.
[Copyrights VRR@NYC2011, see http://SonofBastiat.blogspot.com
for the rest of the other blogs]
Sunday, October 16, 2011
"The Suicide of the West" by James Burnham
A Commentary by Son of Bastiat
“Its
author maintains that western suicidal tendencies lie not so much in the lack
of resources or military
power, but through an erosion of intellectual, moral and spiritual factors
abundant in modern western society and the mainstay of liberal psychology”
[James Burnham’s 1964classic, SUICIDE OF THE WEST, remains a startling account on the nature of the
modern era. It offers a profound, in depth analysis of what is happening in the
world today by putting into focus the intangible, often vague doctrine of
American liberalism. It parallels the loosely defined liberal ideology rampant
in American government and institutions, with the ebb, flow, growth and climax
and the eventual decline and death of both ancient and modern civilizations.
Gateway Editions Review].
This essay, the second on the author’s research into
societal decline and self-annihilation, expands the themes that were explored
in his first essay on America’s
welfare state catastrophe (“America’s
Suicide Attempt by Paul Johnson”}. It broadens their application beyond America to include
entire societies as well (“Suicide of the
West by J. Burnham”). Why be preoccupied with morbid topics such as
societies in decline? Answer: Because it turns out that a common theme
permeates the largely unconscious act of terminating country and societal
existence: moral cowardice and inner rot. The implosion of the Welfare State
and the decay of Western societies are phenomena with deep moral roots. This
essay argues that the RH Bill is but another manifestation of this deeply
seated death wish that leads to societal suicide.
Population Control as a Systems Error Tragedy
Controlling population growth is societal suicide? But wait,
aren’t the methods of population control (from contraception to abortion all
the way down to euthanasia) precisely used to keep society from “eating its
seed” in order to ensure its survival and progress, which is the antithesis of
self-destruction? It isn’t paradoxical for a society to ensure survival by
killing its own. Like the neutron bomb that can kill people while keeping their
homes and buildings intact, survival decisions premised on resource intake and
outgo calculations are based on a cynical and depraved view of human nature.
What looks rational among non-living ecologies such as factories or cities does
not apply to human populations and similar self-aware organisms which are at
root, complex, dynamic and adaptive. This tragedy that lies at the root of all
Malthusian-type analysis is also based on a flawed conceptual understanding of
systems.
Complex systems are usually analyzed by simplifying their
underlying structure, a process of successive reduction by taking away parts or
relationships and variables that a systems analyst considers irrelevant to the
goal at hand (in the case of population, some decision rule that maximizes
utility under a resource constraint). There is nothing odd with organisms
limiting the scope of their efforts to make sense of the complex world, if
simplification is done to conserve energy. Where complications arise is when
the basic reductive impulse comes from outside so that values external to the
system primarily determine which factors are ”extraneous” or which variables
are “irrelevant” to a goal that may not be compatible with the system’s own.
Known as “the outside observer problem”, such arbitrary exclusions result in
models wherein observers’ biases and not members’ values drive the system’s
observed behavior. While all representations of reality reflect both the
conscious or subconscious biases of their observers, models that are
deliberately tweaked by policy incentives in specified directions will tend to
reflect less perfect correspondence between internal behavior and external
perceptions. The trouble arises when such flawed models are claimed to
“objectively represent” reality and employed as basis for policy decisions,
here a policy to control population. Few call out such travesty for the
intellectual dishonesty that it is.
Far from being mere intellectual dross, the “verifiability”
of claims is the stuff of debate between logical positivists (extreme
empiricists for whom naked claims that cannot be verified are meaningless); and
the modern philosophers of science such as Kuhn (for whom scientific methods
cannot verify the truth due to the observer bias and the fact that cultural and
institutional factors influence perceptions of what is claimed as truth).
Replace “scientific method” with “statistical tests” and one can grasp the
enormity of this policy depravity that in the US now snuffs out the life of an
unborn child every 100 seconds, at which rate an entire society turns over in
less than five years. Ironically a policy promulgated to keep society from
“wasting its seed” is self-annihilating itself.
The Harmful Effects of Erroneous Policies
If this is correct then propositions like “reducing population growth is a requisite of
economic progress” or positive claims such as “population increases consumption and hence retards growth by reducing
capital accumulation”; or “artificial
methods of reproduction such as sterilization allows families to raise better quality
offspring” all the way to the most sophisticated demographic models that
are the basis of official population control policies have to be seen for what
they are in essence – incomplete, inaccurate and simplistic expressions of very
complex relationships that mostly reflect the biases of their advocates. They
produce misleading conclusions about the impacts of population control policies
on societies by exaggerating their positive effects on economic variables while
underestimating or even omitting their negative long run influences on
intangible factors crucial to societal balance and growth.
If this is not devastating enough, the coup de grace is
delivered by nonlinear dynamical systems theory: the fact is that statistical
correlations are little more than exercises in ferreting out significant
(p<0.05) reduced form relationships from historically sampled data. But live
systems like human populations are not only dynamically reactive but
anticipatory, meaning that they are capable of purposeful adjustment to varying
stimulus in un-anticipatable (or even contrarian) ways that are rarely
reflected in historical data used by correlation models. It is this adaptive
behavior of dynamic living systems, especially their unpredictable non-linear
responses to stimuli, that makes statistical models so woefully inadequate in
establishing cause and effect relationships. The effects show up in
“irrational” and “outlier” behaviors that are filtered out as atypical data: savings-poor
families that find ways to send all children to school, rich taxpayers that
bust up revenue forecasts as marginal tax rates rise; countries whose GDPs
increase as their informal sectors expand, welfare programs that nurture low
productivity and anti-social values. It is these “atypical” system behaviors
caused by the arbitrary exclusion of unknown factors that renders ludicrous the
claimed power of population control policy failures in explaining the relative
disparities in economic performance between the Philippines and its neighbors;
such simplistic models could never have foreseen the grave disaster that
aggressive population control could have brought the Philippines to if 30 years
later it had no skilled labor to export. Policy technicians are better served
by reading less econometric books and more philosophical tracts by philosophers
such as Popper who believed that rational methods cannot validate the truth
value of models and propositions involving human beings whose decisions are
intertwined with reason and motivations that can never be satisfactorily
captured by such weak models. [Incidentally Popper also offered the same
“falsifiability” thesis as basis for claim testing which econometrics deals
poorly with, being about hypothesis testing but not about decisions].
The Ideology that Underpins this Intellectual Error
Statistical methods that do not adequately capture the
irrational quirks of dynamically adaptive systems merely probabilistically
model traits that dispose individuals towards potential behavioral tendencies;
as such they capture traits that dispose, but not sufficiently explain why they
actualize specific behaviors. The set of beliefs, philosophies and world views
that prime such observed behaviors is at its core an ideology that traces its
roots to a fundamental way of thinking about reality that descended from Post
Renaissance thought. It goes by the term Rationalism, and its modern offspring
called Liberalism.
In contrast to the traditional
(Aristotelian/Thomistic/Augustinian) view of human nature which had a permanent
and unchanging essence; where man is corrupt and limited in potential, so that
his fate is tragic unless saved by Divine Intervention, Rationalism/Liberalism,
(to quote Burnham) – “holds that there is nothing intrinsic to the nature of
man that makes it impossible for human society to achieve the goals of peace,
freedom, justice and well-being which liberals define as (the accoutrements) of
a “good society”. Burnham elaborates on Liberalism by quoting Oakeshott –
“Liberalism is confident that reason and rational science, without appeal to
revelation, faith, custom or intuition can both comprehend the world and solve
its problems”. . . “free from obligations to any authority save for the
authority of reason . . He is at once skeptical (because there is almost no
opinion, habit, belief, nothing so firmly rooted and so widely held that he
hesitates to question; and optimistic (because the rationalist never doubts the
power of his reason to determine the worth of a thing, the truth of an opinion
or propriety of an action”.
What follows from such a mistaken view of human nature is
obvious (again quoting Burnham) – “the peaceful, just, free, virtuous,
prosperous society is inevitable or scheduled to come on condition that human
beings behave rationally by accepting the liberal ideology, program and
leadership” (emphasis and italics supplied by the author). Policies to
keep population in check, whether through preventing conception, abortion,
passive deprivation or euthanasia, are examples of programs that liberals want
to impose on societies (especially its vulnerable members) as way to achieve
the “good society” outcome. As explained above such conclusions are both
methodologically flawed but epistemologically unsound, and now are shown to be
the product of an ideology that seeks to remake societies in its own vision
regardless of what the consequences to overall society are. Such is the death
wish that ideology buys.
How Western Societies Really Die
“What they are saying
to us today is that if you want to keep the Federal government open you have to
throw women under the bus” is how Sen. P. Murray (D., Wash) depicted the
contentious budget debates among Republicans and Democrats in which funding for
Planned Parenthood (a pro-abortion group) came close to shutting down the US
government. The terrible fact is that the economic future of the US is held
hostage by a flawed issue that doesn’t even represent 0.15 % of a budget that
liberal policies have larded with entitlements so that cuts of 1-2 % are now
called “draconian”. If the US
economy does implode it will not be from wars or alien invasions, it will be
from a tragic decision to kill unborn babies.
Friday, October 7, 2011
The Fate of Rational Men: The Enigma that was Steven Jobs
By Son of Bastiat
“Stay hungry. Stay foolish” – Jobs’ 2005 commencement address at Stanford
Why a Rational Life Means Bearing with Unhappiness
Copyrights by V. Ricasio, NYC 2011
“Stay hungry. Stay foolish” – Jobs’ 2005 commencement address at Stanford
The above quote that Steve Jobs
ended his 2005 Stanford U commencement address with, (and could well have
served as his motto if he had one), comes as an admonition and final sentence
in “The Whole Earth Catalogue” a book that in a NY Times 10/06/11 obituary Jobs
said “had influenced him greatly as a young man”, adds a final touch of mystery
to the enigmatic life that ended yesterday. In the coming days, as the world
pays its deep respects to his memory, accolades like “iconic”, “visionary” and
“genius” will be heaped on him; he will be compared to Edison, Ford,
Rockefeller and Walton, all rolled into one.
When it comes to lexicon, there is
no doubt that Jobs was every word and every lofty idea that embody them. Do
these terms describe him? More frankly: Who is the Steven Jobs who passed away
yesterday?
The Fables of Successful Enterprise
Begin with the romantic stories,
likely to be mythical, of how supermen come to the world of ordinary men.
Months after Steve’s birth his short family life ends with his mother giving
him up for adoption, because her father wouldn’t abide having a Syrian for a
son-in-law. In the annals of enterprise, drastic early life experiences such as
a divorce, adoption, abandonment (or in Gates’ case a latchkey childhood)
always mark the tipping point separating mortal from immortal. Circumstances
like extreme penury or, in Jobs case his family’s lack of means to send him to
college, help reinforce the romantic narrative of outsiders rising,
phoenix-like, from nothingness to rarefied heights reserved exclusively for the
anointed.
Recent articles have regaled
readers with probably apocryphal tales of Jobs retrieving empty soda cans and
turning them in for cash; and walking 7 miles across the Reed College campus
(Portland, OR) in order to save on fare so he could partake of low cost meals at
a Krishna temple. One who can get admitted to Reed cannot be that mendicant.
The height of all this icon-buffing, of course, are stories of dropping out of
college (he left after a semester) “in order not to deplete my parents’
savings” that if true, catapults its object of devotion into the realms of
iconic dropouts who not only left school because they found it a waste of time,
but out of love for their struggling parents. A common enough story in the
Third World, it is something so rare and edifying and coveted that another drop
out (Gates) could only perhaps fantasize about. Those stories can only enhance
the image of a spare, disciplined and concerned upbringing, fitting right in
with the classical narratives of success so dear to historians of enterprise.
The Truth Value of Hard Facts
In a class by themselves are the
fables that inspire awe and bestow on their tellers the status of
“entrepreneurs par excellence”. There is the “Tale of the Garage” where things
as novel and as earthshaking as digital personal computers see the first light
of day in a place as decrepit and dingy as where the family car is towed at
night. Only the fact that this event did not happen centuries ago keeps a
manger full of braying horses and donkeys from being used as the backdrop to
such a historical event. Instead it
turns out that most stories about incubating ventures in garages are a load of
c_ _p; the most likely places, in declining order of frequency are: the kitchen
table (for convenient access to the coffeepot); followed by the tool shack for
easier reach of tools and parts; and last at the local library most incubators
are likely to be mental than physical at least at the onset. It is possible
that Jobs briefly stored his PC parts in his family garage, but he also rented
an office in town.
Next come “The Bootstrap”
narratives, where the hero always manages to come up with the key insight, the
dramatic solution to the problem that had bugged all before that fateful
moment. In Jobs’ case, this consisted in stories of how the first personal
computer was put together in trial and error experiments using parts and ideas
learned in countless sessions with fellow members of the Homebrew Computer
Club, an association of electronic hobbyists based in Menlo Park. The reality
about the first PC is far from that; a few years previously, the Altos, the
first working PC was invented in, of all places, Albuquerque, New Mexico and
kits came into the hands of and were assembled by Jobs and his putative partner
Steve Wozniack. With Apple’s startup capital placed at all of $ 1,300, their
tinkering could not have been of a kind sufficient to radically redesign an
existing and working personal computer. So much, then, for the appellation
“father of the personal computer” that has been attached to Jobs’ name.
Even more dramatic exaggerations
are tales of how Apple II (in its advanced models) revolutionized the personal
computer with its incorporation (“adaptation”) of the GUI (graphic user
interface) and mouse, two of the most crucial innovations that along with
Visicalc, accelerated the use of personal computers. Again, unfortunately both
were invented somewhere else, in Palo Alto’s XEROX Parc, then a leading
technology company in Silicon Valley and in the Northeast, where it was
originally based. Jobs himself acknowledged this in an interview, remarking how
“apocalyptic” an experience it was to watch the Altos PC being controlled by a
mouse from commands displayed in a graphical medium and not by typing
statements or codes the way IBM PC and other computers did. So much again, for
“bold pioneering”.
In fact Jobs was neither an
expert in computer technology (Wozniack was the hardware guy) nor in its
programming; for some reason he failed to foresee the possibilities in what would
later on become the world wide web – now a much bigger field than personal
computing itself and which could prove to be its ultimate Nemesis. This
technology was created by Tim Berners Lee, who worked as a programmer at NEXT.
Jobs’ unique talent was not in technology development but in envisioning its
social interface and application. This proves that there are few payoffs in
high technology per se; what is prized and truly creates value is technology
that addresses a need, in the PC’s case, needs without customers or that
present ones fail to see. In creating the IPhone, IPod and IPad Jobs deserved
to be called a true visionary.
Stunning Success, but at what price?
All the foregoing stellar
accomplishments, even when corrected, would have been more than enough to fill
in ten lifetimes for an ordinary man; but as Steve Jobs was not an ordinary
man, it is only fair to also look at their antitheses, exceptional not being
synonymous with perfect.
The most telling of Jobs’ known
failings was his aloofness, his brash, almost tyrannical style especially in
the early years. Whereas outsiders to his world were led to believe that he was
“charismatic, altruistic and genial” when dealing with others, in the company
of his closest friends and associates he was far from such especially early on.
In private he was perfunctory, formal and even cold especially about personal
things, except when he was inquiring about the status of projects or matters
related to work in general. He was suave and even charming with customers, but
those who observed, felt and experienced his stern lashings knew that Jobs’
primary concerns were functional, sometimes to the point of being harsh if
expectations were not met.
Jobs’ demands from his associates and subordinates
were so total that Apple’s culture was for a while sublimated to it; many have
pointed out how his successor Tim Cook
has taken on Jobs’ appearance and mannerisms, a sign of how loyalty to a
man can take on blind emulation. Personality cults are commonplace among CEOs,
but egoistic values can be devastating during successions, and while Jobs did
not seem to indulge it, he did not discourage it either.
As if that was not bad enough,
this lack of warmth extended even to his relationships with close kin, to the
point of meeting a sister only late in adulthood, who wrote a novel that
portrayed him in an unflattering light. About his immediate family made up of a
wife and three children (and a child from a former sweetheart) little is known;
Jobs himself was aware of how remote he was to his children. Many successful
men are driven to the extremes of limiting family interactions or keeping such
affairs private.
In this regard, Jobs was a stereotype, but one can question its wisdom when used to rebuff his 80 year old biological father’s request, expressed in calls and emails, for a brief chance to meet him before it was all over. Perhaps he felt uncomfortable with digging up the painful memories of his abandonment; perhaps he wanted to avoid legal issues that could ensue, something which his old man disavowed the slightest interest in, saying: “All I wanted was to have a cup of coffee with my son”. Today that one chance in a trillion is gone forever because of Steve’s hard stonewalling. Such is the lot of people who are too rational – they give up the few opportunities to be happy with those who are close to them.
In this regard, Jobs was a stereotype, but one can question its wisdom when used to rebuff his 80 year old biological father’s request, expressed in calls and emails, for a brief chance to meet him before it was all over. Perhaps he felt uncomfortable with digging up the painful memories of his abandonment; perhaps he wanted to avoid legal issues that could ensue, something which his old man disavowed the slightest interest in, saying: “All I wanted was to have a cup of coffee with my son”. Today that one chance in a trillion is gone forever because of Steve’s hard stonewalling. Such is the lot of people who are too rational – they give up the few opportunities to be happy with those who are close to them.
Why a Rational Life Means Bearing with Unhappiness
A clue to this enigma is seen in
his interior life: except for a youthful dalliance with Buddhism Jobs has never
affiliated with any formal worship or faith. Spare in his lifestyle, he was not
a materialist, let alone a hedonist. At the same time he was never big on
philanthropy, once setting up a humanitarian foundation only to disband and
divert its funds to acquire PIXAR. At a pledging session held for wealthy
businessmen, he was among those who did not commit to donate, and Apple today
is a rare American company that has no formal corporate giving program or
philanthropic endeavors. If it has, it is nominal.
Stay hungry. Stay foolish. What could Steve Jobs have had in mind
when he cited this quote in his 2005 commencement address? It means simply
this: that total devotion to one’s calling means keeping away (staying hungry)
from the pleasures of material success, family, personal relations and even
faith. In this he was a cold, unsentimental and rational being, finding the
greatest meaning in achievement. At the same time he felt that accolades or
ties ultimately amounted to nothing, fleeting as they are in life, and counting
for nothing after death. This is why he believed that quests for fame or
relationships are ultimately foolish.
One will never be able to know exactly
what thoughts played inside Jobs’ head as he lived his final days, but if
Freud’s insights on un-reconciled death are of any use, one can deduce that he
probably was in great sorrow, despite it being said that he died peacefully.
This is why to the end he resisted exchanging a few words with his expectant
father; the rational side of him knew that there was no use.
Copyrights by V. Ricasio, NYC 2011
Monday, September 5, 2011
When Jobs Disappear for Good
Work's Disappearance Signals the Start of a New Economy
By Son of BastiatToday September 5, millions of Americans take a day off in observance of Labor Day, the one day in in the year when they pause to think about the nature and prospects of the task that engages their time and attention more than any other. It will not be a positive assessment given the dreary facts and prospects pertaining to US employment; last Friday the government reported zero job growth. But as this essay will attempt to do, such introspection can also provide the perspective so necessary to survive this looming (and inevitable) tragedy so man can face a future wherein work finally disappears.
Some Dimensions of this Problem
While this essay focuses on American employment performance, its conclusions have universal applicability – some of the trends identified here have earlier been observed in the UK, then in Europe and Japan, and now in the US as well; it will also become the fate of China, Korea and the rest of the NIEs as their economies mature. One cause is demographics (“the quiet leveler of all proud peoples”); others are subtle changes in cultural attitudes towards work, as well as in the fundamental assumptions that underpin the market economy. While this conveys a flavor of inevitability to this problem, in fact the causes run deeper, all the way to metaphysical issues that sages have debated for the last 2000 yrs.
For one, the US true unemployment rate is not the 14 million who are not working (for 9.1 %) that makes the news, but the 16.5 % that doesn’t. This higher figure includes 8.8 million part timers (5.7%) who report themselves as “actively looking for permanent work but can’t find one”, and a further 2.6 million (1.7 %) of frictionally unemployed folks who have stopped looking for work because they have given up or are sorting out problems that keep them from looking for either part or full time work. In the underdeveloped countries, reported unemployment rates usually hover between 10-15 %; unofficial rates that include under and frictionally employed could reach up to as high as 30-40 %. Dry statistics on unemployment describe but one aspect of this multi-faceted problem but not its meaning.
For another, absolute numbers of unemployed and unemployment rates omit what labor economists call the “growth elasticity of employment” meaning the responsiveness of job creation to the growth of the overall economy. The author has not calculated the post-recession values for the US but at the last time he did (back in early 2000s) this was less than 1.5 (ie, a percentage increase in GDP creates less than 1.5 % in new jobs); and more problematically, this has been on a secular decline from 2.6 to 2.2 and then 1.7 from the 80s to the late 1990s. This figure could only have worsened to perhaps less than 1.0 immediately after the onset of the financial crisis; with today’s 1.5 % GDP growth, employment could be growing at less than 1 % if not fairly close to zero.
Just like its capital-to-GDP counterpart, these statistics serve handily for sizing up the relative efficiencies of alternative job creation proposals. Had the Obama economists done their homework, they would have had second thoughts before pushing for the $ 787 billion stimulus that flopped miserably, in some instances spending $ 500,000 to $ 1 MM to create a single job. This stickiness of job creation has structural and institutional issues that underlie them. Why the Obama administration believes that another $ 250 billion of stimulus spending will finally nudge employment growth is a sign of their desperation, akin to throwing money to see if something sprouts.
The Negative Forces Behind Unemployment
In increasing orders of “controllability” the following are the principal causes of the current (and most recent) unemployment problems:
a). Recession. Naturally, the slump in economic activity should explain the largest and most recent drop in job creation performance. The post-crisis US economy which is now clocked as growing anemically between 1-2% is the dominant reason for its lackluster job creation performance (both due to real job losses and slow job growth relative to its long term norm), which are entirely two separate things even though they are caused by the same economic weakness. It is interesting to isolate though, how much of US’ dismal job creation is due to the recession, and how much is due to an apparent slowdown in the global economy as well – which based on Maddison’s secular studies have declined from 2-3 % prior to 1970s to less than 2 % since then. This latter phenomenon, seldom factored in job creation programs, underscores the even more intractable nature of job creation in today’s highly globalized economies.
b). Structural/Frictional. Many studies of long term job creation have identified a core amount of a country’s labor force that will never leave its “unemployed” or “underemployed’ workers’ ranks. In the post-recession US economy, this rate hovers at a high of 45 % of the total labor force, a figure likely to be skewed by the excessively bad economy, but in the past has stayed at around half that figure. This rate though has crept upwards from single digits (during the 60s boom) to the low double digits (12-15 %) of the 80s, to the middle 20%s range since late 90s. The main reason for this is globalization’s leveling effects on wages and benefits, wherein newly hired and lower paid (relative to developed nations’) workers in emerging and developing countries act as an overhang (a put option) on the latter countries’ abilities to hire workers at higher wage and benefit levels. A similar but difficult to quantify factor is the palpable deterioration in Western cultural values and attitudes towards work, which have tended to increase supervision and hiring costs (due to worker lifestyle and location choices). Together these propel the arbitraging of work offshore, and the trend towards contingent (part time) jobs domestically.
c). Policy Errors and Hubris. A very odd but quite powerful contributor to long term unemployment is the predilection of politicians to design and emplace policies that adversely affect incentives to create jobs and/or maintain them. Mainly these policies inhibit hiring because of their impact on costs (of legal compliance and job compensation) but recently the uncertainties stoked by regulations and government interference in the private sector have outweighed even those costs, which are difficult to pass on to consumers. Obama’s recent policies exemplify this job destroying and job growth inhibiting tendencies: Obama Care which will greatly increase employers’ staffing costs; air quality standards that will saddle factories’ with higher operating costs and capital outlays; prohibition on oil drilling and transportation which will make the US hostage to extortionate oil prices; onerous reporting burdens and compliance costs in order to track cash transactions and implement a VAT type tax (both of which were fortunately abandoned). But of even more serious import to business are the current administration’s heavy handed and unprecedented interference in private business in such matters as: cramming down and brazenly eliminating creditors’ interest in the Chrysler restructuring; the forcible bearing by businesses and households of high energy costs in order to subsidize alternative energy; the decision to penalize Boeing for trying to take its aircraft assembly operation to a “right-to-work state” and lately suing to intimidate banks for alleged fraudulent sales of MBS to FHA and Fannie/Freddie, on top of earlier policies to control banks’ internal compensation policies and operations through restrictive laws like Dodd-Frank which along with SarBox have discouraged risk taking and innovation, and likely explains their reticence to lend to businesses. Few of these concerns seem to deter with the bureaucracies that push them aggressively.
It must be frankly admitted that some of these policies have great merit in light of evidence showing that ineffective enforcement (of existing regulations) have contributed to the financial crises and the worsening of the environment. But sudden implementation and even more seriously, incorrectly timed and non-transparent (intimidating) enforcement calculated to please interest groups such as unions and environmentalists, have created so much uncertainty and hesitation among businesses to create jobs that further hampered the recovery of the US economy. It is seriously indicative of a severe dearth of experienced business hands in the Obama administration, a further indictment of its naivety and hubris if not delusiveness about the real prospects of reforming US society under the dire situation it is in.
These three negative forces conspire to artificially eliminate work before its naturally sanctioned time.
The Final (Positive) Destiny of Work is Its Disappearance
All the preceding factors can be viewed as “cyclical” in the sense that much of their adverse impacts on employment could quickly ease up once the global economy snaps out of its funk and leaps onto a higher growth trajectory. While this happens every now and then (“cyclical”) the chance of this event secularly persisting, while not zero, is not very high, as Angus Maddison’s long term (from 1000 AD) growth studies have shown. If this is correct, then a sustained growth of jobs is itself a chimera. The only task remaining is to explain why this is so, and the author believes that ultimately the reason is rooted in technological and metaphysical forces that are happening beyond anyone’s power to control:
i. Dematerialization. The world has entered into a phase (of its evolution as a cosmic entity) whereby growth is no longer anchored on increasing consumption of material goods and processing of resources as had been its mode since the Industrial Revolution. It is too soon to say that this confirms what mystic writers have divined ten centuries ago, whereby increasing intelligence and not materiality will be the driving force towards the final destiny of the cosmos. As employment is but the tangible result and manifestation of materiality, it should thus be expected to decline and diminish in the long run future.
ii. Speed and Mobility. The accelerating rate of change (that dematerialization makes possible) is nature’s way of coping with the complexity that poses as the ultimate challenge to human intelligence. Unfortunately, such speeds as are made possible by the internet also cut out the intermediation and value of information that provides the last refuge for job seekers (if they have not been eliminated by reducing the length of the work cycle and physical stocks that are essential for dealing with uncertainty).
iii. Automata. A culmination of the trend towards increasing complexity and intelligence it is the final process that will abolish work, and it occurs when most human activities are performed by robots and mind-machine interfaces so that the only labor needed will be that which is required to maintain these man-machine systems, health, artistic expression and entertainment (human creativity). There will be no other need for work and consequently work will not serve the same purpose as it has served man so far – the means for survival. Instead, work will serve as the creative vehicle for expressing man’s quest for perfection. At this stage after de-mass and velocity have eliminated work, only creativity remains.
Since life did not endure eons of severe mutation and selection pressure only to vanish meaninglessly, there must be something superior that will make it possible for Man to survive after work disappears. After all, Nature abhors a vacuum and perfection is an upward (never downward) moving spiral. What exactly is this ingredient the absence of which will mean that the 14.5 billon year Cosmic Experiment must have all been for naught, or at best a burst of randomness?
The Natural Forces that Will Replace Work (After Jobs are Gone)
It all seems so far-fetched considering the problems sprouting all around him but if one thinks about it deep enough considering the above premises, there is only one logical outcome for modern Man: he can only go so far by dividing the remaining work to its even more basic elements (hoping to somehow “spread” it but at the cost of greater loss of satisfaction and meaning. Ultimately he will have no choice but to change himself and society’s (including the economy’s) basic foundations beginning from purpose to means, to make him survive in a dematerialized, volatile and uncertain world. He must do this because such a change is needed to offset the negative forces that made work disappear unnaturally.
The author has come to accept what seems strange to say especially in this Age of Separation (between Matter and the Spirit) but it is really nothing else but the transcendent values of love and concern for fellowmen that will let man survive the loss of employment and fill this huge void created as the cosmos hurtles towards its destiny. A society and economy restructured along transcendent lines will not only dispense of work but banish this materialistic concern for survival. Weird it sounds but quite very logical.
P. T. de Chardin called it Spirituality. Only a sense of wonder and utter amazement constrains the author from using this term lightly; despite all the flourish that came with it, it all refers to one and the same thing: God who made Man to work by the sweat of his brow if he wanted to survive, is now showing the path to perfection by eliminating that albatross around his neck called work.
Work, especially at meager wages, rather than liberating (“Arbeit macht Frei”) man, has actually condemned him to obscurity.
Copyrights: VRR@NYC@2011
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)